- Want to solve a complex problem? Applied math can help
- Inadequate compensation for lost or downgraded protected areas threatens global biodiversity: Study
- Only 5 women have won the Nobel Prize in physics—recent winners share advice for young women in the field
- Madagascar's mining rush has caused no more deforestation than farming, study finds
- Scientists explore microbial diversity in sourdough starters
MIT World
Excellence is a Shared Path: Working Together for Justice and the Quality of Life
Exploring the past opens up new perspectives on the present and offers ways of navigating a challenging future, these speakers suggest, in a call to action on the occasion of Martin Luther King, Jr.’s birthday.
Susan Hockfield has been “digging into MIT’s history,” where she finds seeds for the institute’s distinct culture. One core aspect of this culture, sustained over MIT’s 150 years, is the idea of “rewarding talent and initiative regardless of social position or pedigree,” says Hockfield. However, as she describes, meritocracy has sometimes been more of an aspiration than reality. Hockfield cites examples of the grudging acceptance of women students in the 19th and early 20th century. In the 1961 centennial, there were only 155 women enrolled in a student body of more than 6,000, she says. “Today, through a conscious and sustained outreach, 45% of undergraduates are now women.”
Although MIT now boasts far more students and faculty of underrepresented minorities, Hockfield says that “opening doors turns out to be the easy part.” It is more difficult ensuring that “those who come from outside the circle of affluence or white privilege can count on a sense of full citizenship.” MIT’s central challenge must be “full inclusion,” states Hockfield, and the Institute should lead the nation in attaining this goal.
Don’t show up at a King celebration, says
Roland Martin, if you do not intend to recommit to “his cause, his ideals and vision.” Martin frets that today’s young people are waiting for the right moment “to take charge and get involved.” It was not always so. In 1955, a handful of pastors in Montgomery, Alabama chose a very young Martin Luther King to lead the city’s improvement association. It was high school and college students who frequently led the charge with lunch counter sit-ins, boycotts, and other protests that launched the Civil Rights movement.
Martin notes the sense of lowered expectations around President Obama’s administration, as if “folks voted, and then said, I’m done, did my part, when in fact, the election was the beginning of a process, not the end.” Young people must “give a damn about something” other than themselves, and understand that the work involved often lasts for years. Martin invokes the Bible’s Nehemiah, who rallied people to rebuild the walls of Jerusalem. “What’s your wall?” he asks: “Literacy? Economic development? HIV/AIDS? The point is, start where you are, then move on to the street, block, neighborhood, nation…”
Martin notes that his audience totals more than the number of those who met half a century ago in the Montgomery church basement, setting in motion a nationwide movement. There is enough “brain power, energy, passion in this room to literally change the world,” he says, and “it’s been done before, we have empirical data to prove it.” Concludes Martin, “It’s time to stop talking, meeting and start leading, whether young or old, to rebuild the crumbling walls in this country.”
Susan Hockfield has been “digging into MIT’s history,” where she finds seeds for the institute’s distinct culture. One core aspect of this culture, sustained over MIT’s 150 years, is the idea of “rewarding talent and initiative regardless of social position or pedigree,” says Hockfield. However, as she describes, meritocracy has sometimes been more of an aspiration than reality. Hockfield cites examples of the grudging acceptance of women students in the 19th and early 20th century. In the 1961 centennial, there were only 155 women enrolled in a student body of more than 6,000, she says. “Today, through a conscious and sustained outreach, 45% of undergraduates are now women.”
Although MIT now boasts far more students and faculty of underrepresented minorities, Hockfield says that “opening doors turns out to be the easy part.” It is more difficult ensuring that “those who come from outside the circle of affluence or white privilege can count on a sense of full citizenship.” MIT’s central challenge must be “full inclusion,” states Hockfield, and the Institute should lead the nation in attaining this goal.
Don’t show up at a King celebration, says
Roland Martin, if you do not intend to recommit to “his cause, his ideals and vision.” Martin frets that today’s young people are waiting for the right moment “to take charge and get involved.” It was not always so. In 1955, a handful of pastors in Montgomery, Alabama chose a very young Martin Luther King to lead the city’s improvement association. It was high school and college students who frequently led the charge with lunch counter sit-ins, boycotts, and other protests that launched the Civil Rights movement.
Martin notes the sense of lowered expectations around President Obama’s administration, as if “folks voted, and then said, I’m done, did my part, when in fact, the election was the beginning of a process, not the end.” Young people must “give a damn about something” other than themselves, and understand that the work involved often lasts for years. Martin invokes the Bible’s Nehemiah, who rallied people to rebuild the walls of Jerusalem. “What’s your wall?” he asks: “Literacy? Economic development? HIV/AIDS? The point is, start where you are, then move on to the street, block, neighborhood, nation…”
Martin notes that his audience totals more than the number of those who met half a century ago in the Montgomery church basement, setting in motion a nationwide movement. There is enough “brain power, energy, passion in this room to literally change the world,” he says, and “it’s been done before, we have empirical data to prove it.” Concludes Martin, “It’s time to stop talking, meeting and start leading, whether young or old, to rebuild the crumbling walls in this country.”
Categories: TemeTV
Excellence is a Shared Path: Student Remarks
In their brief remarks honoring the legacy of Dr. Martin Luther King, Jr., two students strike the theme of collaboration. They touch on the importance of humility and listening to one’s inner voice while pursuing a shared vision of justice and equality.
When she first came to MIT, Khalea Robinson was set to become a builder of bridges and skyscrapers. “Their visibility and permanence appealed to me.” But a talk she attended on some of the world’s pressing problems shook her commitment to this path. Access to clean water, and other issues, should surely count more than her own private engineering goals, she imagined.
But after taking introductory courses in environmental and civil engineering, she realized that she “couldn’t simply fall in line wherever there was a call, because there are so many calls, all of them worthy.” Robinson felt that she should instead look for a field that would “bring forth my initiative, passion, drive, insight and courage,” while also promoting justice and fairness. In a world “full of complex problems that need to be solved by many people,” Robinson believes each of us “has a distinct voice that can and must be raised.”
Pierre Fuller finds a model in Biblical scripture’s Nehemiah, who called on his people to rebuild the walls of Jerusalem one brick at a time, “each man contributing according to his ability.” Fuller recounts that when acquaintances call him a “genius” because he studies at MIT, he points to the help he received during his childhood in Flint, Michigan: his grandmother, a hospital cleaner; a barber friend with a drug record; and his mother -- “who guided me with equal doses of love and tender encouragement, and a wooden paddle and a backhand that would rival Serena Williams.”
Just as Fuller attributes his success to a collective that made unique contributions to his upbringing, he sees the project of building a better world as a function of individuals working together in humility, suppressing personal ambitions, and “replacing a savior mentality with a serving mentality.” The technological innovations MIT sees as the foundation of the future are “only a brick, a small portion of the wall that is to sustain our community.” The academic elite, says Fuller, must seek solutions for communities they serve. All of us “must humble our hearts” to work for “those who come after us, as we have been served by those who come before.”
When she first came to MIT, Khalea Robinson was set to become a builder of bridges and skyscrapers. “Their visibility and permanence appealed to me.” But a talk she attended on some of the world’s pressing problems shook her commitment to this path. Access to clean water, and other issues, should surely count more than her own private engineering goals, she imagined.
But after taking introductory courses in environmental and civil engineering, she realized that she “couldn’t simply fall in line wherever there was a call, because there are so many calls, all of them worthy.” Robinson felt that she should instead look for a field that would “bring forth my initiative, passion, drive, insight and courage,” while also promoting justice and fairness. In a world “full of complex problems that need to be solved by many people,” Robinson believes each of us “has a distinct voice that can and must be raised.”
Pierre Fuller finds a model in Biblical scripture’s Nehemiah, who called on his people to rebuild the walls of Jerusalem one brick at a time, “each man contributing according to his ability.” Fuller recounts that when acquaintances call him a “genius” because he studies at MIT, he points to the help he received during his childhood in Flint, Michigan: his grandmother, a hospital cleaner; a barber friend with a drug record; and his mother -- “who guided me with equal doses of love and tender encouragement, and a wooden paddle and a backhand that would rival Serena Williams.”
Just as Fuller attributes his success to a collective that made unique contributions to his upbringing, he sees the project of building a better world as a function of individuals working together in humility, suppressing personal ambitions, and “replacing a savior mentality with a serving mentality.” The technological innovations MIT sees as the foundation of the future are “only a brick, a small portion of the wall that is to sustain our community.” The academic elite, says Fuller, must seek solutions for communities they serve. All of us “must humble our hearts” to work for “those who come after us, as we have been served by those who come before.”
Categories: TemeTV
The Future of Finance
In his keynote address, Robert Merton chooses not to focus on the financial crisis. It is clear to him there were “fools and knaves,” as well as “many structural elements that would have happened even if people were well behaved and well informed” -- risks are simply “embedded in our systems.” Instead, Merton explores how financial engineering is essential in preparing for the inevitable next crisis, and in solving critical challenges. “The world has changed; we can’t go back. Let’s talk about what we should do going forward.”
To illustrate society’s need for financial innovation, Merton uses “a live case study:” the vast problem of retirement funding. In the past decade, stock market declines and falling interest rates have hit mainstream employer pension plans hard. Municipal pension plans may be underfunded to the tune of three trillion dollars. (“It makes the S&L crisis look like nothing.”) But people seek, and are due, “the standard of living during retirement they enjoyed in the latter part of their work life.”
Generally, determining this standard of living means adding up likely medical, housing and general consumption costs, and Merton describes how to target such retirement income. The main ways to achieve the desired goal are by saving more, working longer or taking more risk. Merton would like to design a software-based tool for ordinary people, simple on the user end, complex on the provider end, which would serve as a “next generation pension solution,” offering a way to manipulate the key variables in retirement income and demonstrate potential financial outcomes. This tool would help users continuously optimize risk to help them reach their retirement funding goals.
There are regulatory obstacles now to the implementation of such a method on a widespread basis, and a gap between how managers, advisers and financial institutions think about pension assets, and what Merton has in mind. Nevertheless, he says, “What we need to do for most of the people who don’t have extra money and must do the most with their assets is deliver a simple, easy to use, and if they don’t use it still gets them there, solution.” Merton acknowledges those who think the giant problem of pension funding can be solved by what’s already available -- bond and equity markets, bank loans – and who hanker “to get rid of all the complexity, go back to 1930, ’50 or ’80.” From his perspective, this means “throwing away a lot of what you could do, because the market-proven strategies people have developed and used…can do a much better job for people.”
To illustrate society’s need for financial innovation, Merton uses “a live case study:” the vast problem of retirement funding. In the past decade, stock market declines and falling interest rates have hit mainstream employer pension plans hard. Municipal pension plans may be underfunded to the tune of three trillion dollars. (“It makes the S&L crisis look like nothing.”) But people seek, and are due, “the standard of living during retirement they enjoyed in the latter part of their work life.”
Generally, determining this standard of living means adding up likely medical, housing and general consumption costs, and Merton describes how to target such retirement income. The main ways to achieve the desired goal are by saving more, working longer or taking more risk. Merton would like to design a software-based tool for ordinary people, simple on the user end, complex on the provider end, which would serve as a “next generation pension solution,” offering a way to manipulate the key variables in retirement income and demonstrate potential financial outcomes. This tool would help users continuously optimize risk to help them reach their retirement funding goals.
There are regulatory obstacles now to the implementation of such a method on a widespread basis, and a gap between how managers, advisers and financial institutions think about pension assets, and what Merton has in mind. Nevertheless, he says, “What we need to do for most of the people who don’t have extra money and must do the most with their assets is deliver a simple, easy to use, and if they don’t use it still gets them there, solution.” Merton acknowledges those who think the giant problem of pension funding can be solved by what’s already available -- bond and equity markets, bank loans – and who hanker “to get rid of all the complexity, go back to 1930, ’50 or ’80.” From his perspective, this means “throwing away a lot of what you could do, because the market-proven strategies people have developed and used…can do a much better job for people.”
Categories: TemeTV
Finance in Action
Stewart Myers introduces the panelists as distinguished academics and practitioners who share not only their status as MIT alums, but also their innovative application of finance theory to entrepreneurship. “They were in the middle of the action,” says Myers.
Douglas Breeden “grew up in the chicken business” so it is unsurprising that his financial path began with a classroom exercise for forecasting egg futures. His career moved eventually to analyzing the virtues of mortgage products. Models to estimate risks in asset-backed securities and their expected profits are very sensitive to such complex influences as interest rates, prepayment rates, and ominously rising loan-to-value ratios, he notes.
Breeden observes that a slight perturbation in one of these factors can have a major impact on a prediction, or even reverse the direction of the economic result. “This is why smart people have a hard time making money with these securities,” he comments. Breeden says the theories are great, yet so are the challenges of applying them. He appeals for “a little bit of sympathy for the financial application people.”
Eugene Flood emphasizes “structure” as the sine qua non to define problems and achieve results throughout a large organization. Involvement in areas ranging from international finance to proprietary trading to human resources taught him “how to think of the firm as a whole.” Thanks to this broad exposure within the investment business, Flood recognizes that a comprehensive, integrated approach goes far toward success of the enterprise. He forms multidisciplinary teams and stresses a consistent philosophy, supported by “constructive debate” and active reinforcement of ideas by management.
On systemic risk, Flood cautions “we can get very good at pulling problems apart,” but we cannot overlook the iterative, progressive effects of shifting one thing “and that affects something else and that affects something else…” In keeping with his holistic view of business operations, he advises taking account of “everything that moves when one thing starts to change.”
Bennett Golub recounts the inception of financial engineering in the traditional sense of engineering a physical object. In 1985, while at a major investment bank, he used CAD-CAM software to design new types of mortgage-backed securities. “We would grind it out, …studying all the parameters, tuning these things up, and calibrating them precisely to what the different investors wanted, trying to extract arbitrage in the process.” After a few years, he continues, “Instead of making money the old-fashioned way -- earning it -- people discovered you could obfuscate,” that is, hide the risk. “You could get people to pay you for things that they probably shouldn’t.” That led in turn to “what we call risk management…Know what you own and understand how it behaves.”
Golub acknowledges that the financially engineered models that kept him ahead of clients “had challenges along the way. From the beginning, I always tried to think about having some humility in the analytics,” he admits.
As a financial mathematician, Robert Jarrow creates and implements models to manage interest rate and credit risks. He constructed a “reduced form model” to address defaults across the business cycle. Because credit rating agencies were among the largest users of earlier flawed models, and “many other financial institutions depended upon them to get the risk measures right,” the economy suffered a disastrous cascade. He maintains faith nonetheless, saying “I believe financial engineering models are the solution” but we need better education on how to use them for risk management.
Jarrow now studies how hedging techniques should respond to asset price bubbles, and “how to include a realistic financial sector in a macroeconomic model.” He aims to develop tools that take account of actual conditions, unlike existing idealized models.
Judy Lewent brought sophisticated theories and analytical methods learned at MIT to key facets of the pharmaceutical industry. For instance, Lewent describes, in Merck’s global activities “we had a very robust framework to understand where our foreign currency risks were and what aspects of those we needed to hedge…to minimize the volatility.” This knowledge helped management allocate resources with reasonable certainty and stability.
Lewent used Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate the company’s portfolio, and to examine the questions: “How do you think about what the right level of R&D spending is, and are you returning the cost of capital to your shareholders?” She put game theory into practice “to help us with a specific pricing decision for a new product launch.” She also applied her MIT training to determine the feasibility of mergers and acquisitions; investigate the most efficient corporate capital structure; and reduce financial risk, enabling Merck to go forward when it became necessary to withdraw a major medicine from the market. Lewent declares, “Theory is great but it really does apply directly to practice.”
Douglas Breeden “grew up in the chicken business” so it is unsurprising that his financial path began with a classroom exercise for forecasting egg futures. His career moved eventually to analyzing the virtues of mortgage products. Models to estimate risks in asset-backed securities and their expected profits are very sensitive to such complex influences as interest rates, prepayment rates, and ominously rising loan-to-value ratios, he notes.
Breeden observes that a slight perturbation in one of these factors can have a major impact on a prediction, or even reverse the direction of the economic result. “This is why smart people have a hard time making money with these securities,” he comments. Breeden says the theories are great, yet so are the challenges of applying them. He appeals for “a little bit of sympathy for the financial application people.”
Eugene Flood emphasizes “structure” as the sine qua non to define problems and achieve results throughout a large organization. Involvement in areas ranging from international finance to proprietary trading to human resources taught him “how to think of the firm as a whole.” Thanks to this broad exposure within the investment business, Flood recognizes that a comprehensive, integrated approach goes far toward success of the enterprise. He forms multidisciplinary teams and stresses a consistent philosophy, supported by “constructive debate” and active reinforcement of ideas by management.
On systemic risk, Flood cautions “we can get very good at pulling problems apart,” but we cannot overlook the iterative, progressive effects of shifting one thing “and that affects something else and that affects something else…” In keeping with his holistic view of business operations, he advises taking account of “everything that moves when one thing starts to change.”
Bennett Golub recounts the inception of financial engineering in the traditional sense of engineering a physical object. In 1985, while at a major investment bank, he used CAD-CAM software to design new types of mortgage-backed securities. “We would grind it out, …studying all the parameters, tuning these things up, and calibrating them precisely to what the different investors wanted, trying to extract arbitrage in the process.” After a few years, he continues, “Instead of making money the old-fashioned way -- earning it -- people discovered you could obfuscate,” that is, hide the risk. “You could get people to pay you for things that they probably shouldn’t.” That led in turn to “what we call risk management…Know what you own and understand how it behaves.”
Golub acknowledges that the financially engineered models that kept him ahead of clients “had challenges along the way. From the beginning, I always tried to think about having some humility in the analytics,” he admits.
As a financial mathematician, Robert Jarrow creates and implements models to manage interest rate and credit risks. He constructed a “reduced form model” to address defaults across the business cycle. Because credit rating agencies were among the largest users of earlier flawed models, and “many other financial institutions depended upon them to get the risk measures right,” the economy suffered a disastrous cascade. He maintains faith nonetheless, saying “I believe financial engineering models are the solution” but we need better education on how to use them for risk management.
Jarrow now studies how hedging techniques should respond to asset price bubbles, and “how to include a realistic financial sector in a macroeconomic model.” He aims to develop tools that take account of actual conditions, unlike existing idealized models.
Judy Lewent brought sophisticated theories and analytical methods learned at MIT to key facets of the pharmaceutical industry. For instance, Lewent describes, in Merck’s global activities “we had a very robust framework to understand where our foreign currency risks were and what aspects of those we needed to hedge…to minimize the volatility.” This knowledge helped management allocate resources with reasonable certainty and stability.
Lewent used Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate the company’s portfolio, and to examine the questions: “How do you think about what the right level of R&D spending is, and are you returning the cost of capital to your shareholders?” She put game theory into practice “to help us with a specific pricing decision for a new product launch.” She also applied her MIT training to determine the feasibility of mergers and acquisitions; investigate the most efficient corporate capital structure; and reduce financial risk, enabling Merck to go forward when it became necessary to withdraw a major medicine from the market. Lewent declares, “Theory is great but it really does apply directly to practice.”
Categories: TemeTV
The Growth of Cryptography
It’s not every day that Euclid appears in public with “Alice and Bob,” but in a lecture spanning a few thousand years, Ronald Rivest summons these and other notables in his history of cryptography. While citing milestones of code-making and breaking, Rivest also brings his audience up to date on the latest systems for securing information and communication networks, which owe much to his own research.
Rivest makes quick work of the period before mid- 20th century, but credits the ancient Greeks for prime number factorization -- essential to cryptography -- and elementary ciphers. In the 18th and 19th century, mathematicians delved into number theory and extended techniques of factoring. The twentieth century, with its two world wars and technological advances, established the significance of cryptography on and off the battlefield. Alan Turing’s Enigma machine not only helped the allies win World War II, but catalyzed development of the first generation of computers. MIT professor Claude Shannon, who worked with Turing and other cryptanalysts, went on to father the field of information science, leading to the digital age.
In the 1970s came development of public data encryption methods. Academics prevailed against U.S. government efforts to conceal means for encrypting data. In 1977, Rivest’s group at MIT, which included Adi Shamir and Len Adleman, came up with RSA, an elegant algorithm for public-key cryptography that “relies on the difficulty of factoring” primes and which is still widely used. The group was so confident of its encryption method that they offered $100 for breaking a cipher-text based on a 129-digit product of primes. Rivest thought it would take “40 quadrillion years” to solve the challenge. “It was a bad estimate,” he admits.
In fact, a combination of new algorithms and brute computing power cracked the text in 1994 (“The Magic Words are Squeamish Ossifrage”). Technological and theoretical advances have made possible improved encryption methods, and ways of authenticating and securing data. Faster computers may someday “make factoring a million-digit number easy,” says Rivest. Work is even progressing on a quantum computer (it can only factor the number 15 so far). But code-breaking is also increasingly sophisticated, Rivest warns, as the internet opens up vast new areas of data to cyber-attack.
Rivest sees cryptography blossoming into applications for anonymity, password-based keys, and crypto for smart cards. He has been looking into probabilistic micropayment systems, and techniques to enhance the security and transparency of voting. “Maybe large prime numbers have a role to play in our democracy down the road,” he says.
Rivest makes quick work of the period before mid- 20th century, but credits the ancient Greeks for prime number factorization -- essential to cryptography -- and elementary ciphers. In the 18th and 19th century, mathematicians delved into number theory and extended techniques of factoring. The twentieth century, with its two world wars and technological advances, established the significance of cryptography on and off the battlefield. Alan Turing’s Enigma machine not only helped the allies win World War II, but catalyzed development of the first generation of computers. MIT professor Claude Shannon, who worked with Turing and other cryptanalysts, went on to father the field of information science, leading to the digital age.
In the 1970s came development of public data encryption methods. Academics prevailed against U.S. government efforts to conceal means for encrypting data. In 1977, Rivest’s group at MIT, which included Adi Shamir and Len Adleman, came up with RSA, an elegant algorithm for public-key cryptography that “relies on the difficulty of factoring” primes and which is still widely used. The group was so confident of its encryption method that they offered $100 for breaking a cipher-text based on a 129-digit product of primes. Rivest thought it would take “40 quadrillion years” to solve the challenge. “It was a bad estimate,” he admits.
In fact, a combination of new algorithms and brute computing power cracked the text in 1994 (“The Magic Words are Squeamish Ossifrage”). Technological and theoretical advances have made possible improved encryption methods, and ways of authenticating and securing data. Faster computers may someday “make factoring a million-digit number easy,” says Rivest. Work is even progressing on a quantum computer (it can only factor the number 15 so far). But code-breaking is also increasingly sophisticated, Rivest warns, as the internet opens up vast new areas of data to cyber-attack.
Rivest sees cryptography blossoming into applications for anonymity, password-based keys, and crypto for smart cards. He has been looking into probabilistic micropayment systems, and techniques to enhance the security and transparency of voting. “Maybe large prime numbers have a role to play in our democracy down the road,” he says.
Categories: TemeTV
The Evolution of Financial Technology
An unmistakable glow of nostalgia rises from this reunion of “five of the founding fathers of modern finance,” in the words of Andrew Lo. The speakers reminisce about their start in economics, and their professional lives at MIT, a decades-long era of intense collaboration and creativity that both transformed the academic field and the landscape of real-world finance.
This group of scholars believes they owe much to luck in finding their lives in financial economics. A sympathetic Stanford professor directed Stewart C. Myers to the right doctoral program, at precisely the moment when “big ideas were flowering” in the discipline: efficient markets, agency costs, and most important to Myers, new theories about valuation. A call came from MIT to join the faculty, and Myers began his critical work around the principles of corporate finance, which turned out to have great practical applications. Says Myers, “It’s really good to go out in the world now and talk to CFOs actually using this stuff.”
Raised in a Canadian family that traded in gold,
Myron Scholes was interested in “how things were valued,” but it was a summer job as a computer programmer for university researchers that set his career path. Assisting Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller, Scholes found infectious their “joy of getting results, and asking the next questions.” He came to MIT in 1968, and became fascinated with options, insurance and distributions of portfolios. He met Fischer Black his first summer, which led to the first of many intellectually profitable partnerships, some of which continue to this day.
Among other twists of fate, a switch in grad school from applied mathematics to economics, and the good sense of MIT to offer him a fellowship (following rejections by eight other schools) brought Robert Merton to Cambridge. After taking Paul Samuelson’s mathematical economics course, “the rest was history,” says Merton. “I lived in his office from the end of that class on.” He was hired at graduation by the Sloan School, and joined a “very small group, with no senior faculty. It was like all these kids and nobody to look after them.” They designed courses, did research, “had a blast. The research flowed so fast for us and the students; there was not enough time to do it all. That doesn’t happen often.” Merton’s work was also stimulated by the economic catastrophes of the 1970s, which fed an intense drive to put research around better markets mechanisms into practice.
“I can’t remember a time when I didn’t want to be a professor, and economics seemed special,” says
John C. Cox. In the mid-1970s, the pathbreaking work of Merton, Black, and Scholes offered “plenty of low-lying plums to be picked in the orchard. It seemed like a golden age for capital market theory, so much to do.” The group he joined at MIT has evolved, and the programs expanded, but Cox “has enjoyed every minute” of the past 30 years.
Stephen A. Ross discovered he loved a certain kind of math while taking a course in game theory and linear programming to fulfill his Caltech humanities requirement. But it wasn’t until he attended a mathematical economics seminar focused on MIT work that he realized he was interested in finance. “It was the most fascinating stuff I’d ever heard.” He especially liked the “science” of it, “that theory and data had to relate in some way.”
Ross defends financial engineering and its applications in the wake of the financial crisis. “Derivatives did what they were supposed to do. They spread the risk. The problem is the people who took on the risk didn’t like the fact they lost money.” Scholes wonders about rules that “let 1.5 million contracts go due in the derivatives swap market instantaneously for settlement. It sounds nuts to me.” Says Myers, “It’s true that modern finance is a powerful tool and can be misused, but it’s not a reason to discard the tool. It’s a reason to use it better.”
This group of scholars believes they owe much to luck in finding their lives in financial economics. A sympathetic Stanford professor directed Stewart C. Myers to the right doctoral program, at precisely the moment when “big ideas were flowering” in the discipline: efficient markets, agency costs, and most important to Myers, new theories about valuation. A call came from MIT to join the faculty, and Myers began his critical work around the principles of corporate finance, which turned out to have great practical applications. Says Myers, “It’s really good to go out in the world now and talk to CFOs actually using this stuff.”
Raised in a Canadian family that traded in gold,
Myron Scholes was interested in “how things were valued,” but it was a summer job as a computer programmer for university researchers that set his career path. Assisting Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller, Scholes found infectious their “joy of getting results, and asking the next questions.” He came to MIT in 1968, and became fascinated with options, insurance and distributions of portfolios. He met Fischer Black his first summer, which led to the first of many intellectually profitable partnerships, some of which continue to this day.
Among other twists of fate, a switch in grad school from applied mathematics to economics, and the good sense of MIT to offer him a fellowship (following rejections by eight other schools) brought Robert Merton to Cambridge. After taking Paul Samuelson’s mathematical economics course, “the rest was history,” says Merton. “I lived in his office from the end of that class on.” He was hired at graduation by the Sloan School, and joined a “very small group, with no senior faculty. It was like all these kids and nobody to look after them.” They designed courses, did research, “had a blast. The research flowed so fast for us and the students; there was not enough time to do it all. That doesn’t happen often.” Merton’s work was also stimulated by the economic catastrophes of the 1970s, which fed an intense drive to put research around better markets mechanisms into practice.
“I can’t remember a time when I didn’t want to be a professor, and economics seemed special,” says
John C. Cox. In the mid-1970s, the pathbreaking work of Merton, Black, and Scholes offered “plenty of low-lying plums to be picked in the orchard. It seemed like a golden age for capital market theory, so much to do.” The group he joined at MIT has evolved, and the programs expanded, but Cox “has enjoyed every minute” of the past 30 years.
Stephen A. Ross discovered he loved a certain kind of math while taking a course in game theory and linear programming to fulfill his Caltech humanities requirement. But it wasn’t until he attended a mathematical economics seminar focused on MIT work that he realized he was interested in finance. “It was the most fascinating stuff I’d ever heard.” He especially liked the “science” of it, “that theory and data had to relate in some way.”
Ross defends financial engineering and its applications in the wake of the financial crisis. “Derivatives did what they were supposed to do. They spread the risk. The problem is the people who took on the risk didn’t like the fact they lost money.” Scholes wonders about rules that “let 1.5 million contracts go due in the derivatives swap market instantaneously for settlement. It sounds nuts to me.” Says Myers, “It’s true that modern finance is a powerful tool and can be misused, but it’s not a reason to discard the tool. It’s a reason to use it better.”
Categories: TemeTV
Economic Policy Challenges: Microeconomics and Regulation
Given its contributions to policy and practice in such key sectors as health care, industrial organization and technological innovation, and energy and the environment, microeconomics may not be getting the kind of respect, or at least attention, it deserves, these panelists suggest.
The field helped “produce a revolution in antitrust thinking” in the U.S., says Dennis Carlton. Since the 1960s, the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission have tapped the talent of dozens of PhD economists, who came up with notions like offering incentives (by way of lower fines and leniency) to those who admit participating in corporate cartels. This “simple idea” led to regulatory policy “with large payoffs,” says Carlton. Simulations and modeling help determine whether the government will approve a merger, or step in when corporations become too big. “Emerging hot topics” in antitrust and industrial organization include the use of product bundling; patent law, especially in high tech; control and use of information over the internet; and privacy issues.
Richard Schmalensee calls attention to microeconomics’ generally unrecognized impact on energy and environmental regulations. For instance, cost benefit analysis was applied to the process of making federal environmental rules, and is now “a bipartisan thing… a part of good government.” And much of the country moved away from a traditional model of regulating electric utilities, giving greater scope to competition, after some deep economic thinking about incentives. That’s the good news. Schmalensee finds it “frankly amazing” and occasionally infuriating how economic thinking has not been applied to energy and environmental policy: the idea of drilling our way to energy independence; and the pursuit of renewable energy as a way of tackling climate change while side-stepping market mechanisms to achieve environmental goals. Schmalensee says he loves “the sun and the wind, but let’s get serious.”
“We live in a time of combinatorial innovation,” says
Hal Varian, where digital age inventors can combine components in novel ways, across great distances, in real time. Even small companies “can be born global,” says Varian, becoming in effect “micro multinationals.” Varian sees a transformation of business processes, a “nanoeconomics of the firm,” where the highly networked, computerized organization “makes life more efficient.” There are hundreds of billions in savings when knowledge workers can instantly track information on the web, he says, and host master copies of work “in the cloud” rather than on paper. Another hallmark of the new organization, exemplified by his company Google, is “experimentation and continuous improvement,” accomplished by such technologies as search engines and voice recognition software that learn on the go. Varian sees econometrics as particularly useful in modeling new ventures, and believes that the increasing amount of data generated by the private sector could soon prove useful to the federal government, “enabling a better handle on what’s going on in the economy.”
Economic modeling had a tremendous impact on health care reform legislation, and as public debate rages, economic analysis remains essential in determining which policies will prove practicable, says Mark McClellan. Some key questions awaiting evidence and investigation: On the supply side, can changing the way providers get paid (traditionally fee for service) stem rising health care costs? On the demand side, will consumers accept health insurance plans designed around payment tiers intended to reduce use, with greater out of pocket costs for beneficiaries?
An instructive model for setting up a system offering choice and cost efficiencies may be the 2006 Medicare prescription drug benefit, which McClellan himself implemented. Seniors overwhelmingly switched to cheaper generic and preferred drugs offered by their plans. While government subsidized, the program “is currently running 40% below actuarial and CBO projections.”
The field helped “produce a revolution in antitrust thinking” in the U.S., says Dennis Carlton. Since the 1960s, the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission have tapped the talent of dozens of PhD economists, who came up with notions like offering incentives (by way of lower fines and leniency) to those who admit participating in corporate cartels. This “simple idea” led to regulatory policy “with large payoffs,” says Carlton. Simulations and modeling help determine whether the government will approve a merger, or step in when corporations become too big. “Emerging hot topics” in antitrust and industrial organization include the use of product bundling; patent law, especially in high tech; control and use of information over the internet; and privacy issues.
Richard Schmalensee calls attention to microeconomics’ generally unrecognized impact on energy and environmental regulations. For instance, cost benefit analysis was applied to the process of making federal environmental rules, and is now “a bipartisan thing… a part of good government.” And much of the country moved away from a traditional model of regulating electric utilities, giving greater scope to competition, after some deep economic thinking about incentives. That’s the good news. Schmalensee finds it “frankly amazing” and occasionally infuriating how economic thinking has not been applied to energy and environmental policy: the idea of drilling our way to energy independence; and the pursuit of renewable energy as a way of tackling climate change while side-stepping market mechanisms to achieve environmental goals. Schmalensee says he loves “the sun and the wind, but let’s get serious.”
“We live in a time of combinatorial innovation,” says
Hal Varian, where digital age inventors can combine components in novel ways, across great distances, in real time. Even small companies “can be born global,” says Varian, becoming in effect “micro multinationals.” Varian sees a transformation of business processes, a “nanoeconomics of the firm,” where the highly networked, computerized organization “makes life more efficient.” There are hundreds of billions in savings when knowledge workers can instantly track information on the web, he says, and host master copies of work “in the cloud” rather than on paper. Another hallmark of the new organization, exemplified by his company Google, is “experimentation and continuous improvement,” accomplished by such technologies as search engines and voice recognition software that learn on the go. Varian sees econometrics as particularly useful in modeling new ventures, and believes that the increasing amount of data generated by the private sector could soon prove useful to the federal government, “enabling a better handle on what’s going on in the economy.”
Economic modeling had a tremendous impact on health care reform legislation, and as public debate rages, economic analysis remains essential in determining which policies will prove practicable, says Mark McClellan. Some key questions awaiting evidence and investigation: On the supply side, can changing the way providers get paid (traditionally fee for service) stem rising health care costs? On the demand side, will consumers accept health insurance plans designed around payment tiers intended to reduce use, with greater out of pocket costs for beneficiaries?
An instructive model for setting up a system offering choice and cost efficiencies may be the 2006 Medicare prescription drug benefit, which McClellan himself implemented. Seniors overwhelmingly switched to cheaper generic and preferred drugs offered by their plans. While government subsidized, the program “is currently running 40% below actuarial and CBO projections.”
Categories: TemeTV
Gaza in Crisis
Two speakers steeped in the ongoing crisis of the Middle East describe abominable conditions for Palestinians living inside Gaza, which has been blockaded by Israel since 2007. They demand urgent action for civilian victims, and condemn both the Israeli and U.S. governments for pursuing policies of “genocide.” An impassioned Nancy Murray details daily life inside what has become a 26-mile-long prison, and Noam Chomsky offers background on how this zone of misery came into being, with withering words for those he labels perpetrators.
Murray asks us to imagine living “in a territory which over the past four years has served as a kind of laboratory to find the breaking point of human beings.” Israel has deliberately worked to keep Gaza functioning at the lowest level possible, preventing Palestinians from repairing their war-torn water and sewer infrastructure, and severely limiting food supplies -- literally controlling calorie intake, says Murray. Israel has also blocked the reconstruction of hospitals and clinics to tend to those wounded by war, or suffering mental health trauma from years of harassment. She cites a 2006 study showing that 98% of Gaza children had been subject to violence, tear gas, or home searches.
In a long-term, calculated effort to strangle economic development, Israel has also deprived fishermen of the right to safe maritime areas, and declared the small patches of arable land “to be a no-go zone,” targeting farmers and children attempting to attend school nearby. The education system has also been hard hit, with schools in disrepair, and children “using old shipping containers as classrooms.” If the future looks grim now, Murray believes there is worse to come, with Israel preparing for another round of war, capping “a six decade- long project of destroying resistance to oppression.”
There is no surprise for Noam Chomsky in the tightening vise around Gaza. It is of a piece with years of Israeli disregard for human rights and international law, he argues. The blockade, which began soon after Hamas won the 2006 Palestinian election, is but the latest episode in a history of betrayal, oppression and outright annihilation. Beginning in 1948 and the formation of Israel to 1967 and beyond, the Palestinians have been systematically humiliated and degraded. In spite of efforts by the U.N., and rulings by other international institutions, says Chomsky, Israel, with the backing of the U.S., has been intent on preventing a Palestinian state, and breaking the will of Palestinians. The 1987 Palestinian uprising goaded the Israelis, who since then have made merely a show of peace talks and increased the pace of their settlements on former Palestinian land. Last May, Israel attacked a ship attempting to break the blockade, killing nine people, and though there was an “international outcry,” says Chomsky, Israel continued its siege, decried by Amnesty International and other human rights groups. The change in U.S. administration made no difference, he says. “The U.S. exerts no pressure, but participates actively and crucially in these crimes. The roadblock to peace remains.”
Murray asks us to imagine living “in a territory which over the past four years has served as a kind of laboratory to find the breaking point of human beings.” Israel has deliberately worked to keep Gaza functioning at the lowest level possible, preventing Palestinians from repairing their war-torn water and sewer infrastructure, and severely limiting food supplies -- literally controlling calorie intake, says Murray. Israel has also blocked the reconstruction of hospitals and clinics to tend to those wounded by war, or suffering mental health trauma from years of harassment. She cites a 2006 study showing that 98% of Gaza children had been subject to violence, tear gas, or home searches.
In a long-term, calculated effort to strangle economic development, Israel has also deprived fishermen of the right to safe maritime areas, and declared the small patches of arable land “to be a no-go zone,” targeting farmers and children attempting to attend school nearby. The education system has also been hard hit, with schools in disrepair, and children “using old shipping containers as classrooms.” If the future looks grim now, Murray believes there is worse to come, with Israel preparing for another round of war, capping “a six decade- long project of destroying resistance to oppression.”
There is no surprise for Noam Chomsky in the tightening vise around Gaza. It is of a piece with years of Israeli disregard for human rights and international law, he argues. The blockade, which began soon after Hamas won the 2006 Palestinian election, is but the latest episode in a history of betrayal, oppression and outright annihilation. Beginning in 1948 and the formation of Israel to 1967 and beyond, the Palestinians have been systematically humiliated and degraded. In spite of efforts by the U.N., and rulings by other international institutions, says Chomsky, Israel, with the backing of the U.S., has been intent on preventing a Palestinian state, and breaking the will of Palestinians. The 1987 Palestinian uprising goaded the Israelis, who since then have made merely a show of peace talks and increased the pace of their settlements on former Palestinian land. Last May, Israel attacked a ship attempting to break the blockade, killing nine people, and though there was an “international outcry,” says Chomsky, Israel continued its siege, decried by Amnesty International and other human rights groups. The change in U.S. administration made no difference, he says. “The U.S. exerts no pressure, but participates actively and crucially in these crimes. The roadblock to peace remains.”
Categories: TemeTV
Economic Policy Challenges: Macroeconomics and Fiscal Policy
These economists, MIT PhDs all, ponder what remains in the macroeconomist’s toolkit to pull the U.S., and much of the developed world, out of recession. They discuss aspects of fiscal and monetary policy that may prove useful in spurring recovery, as well as the complicating matter of politics.
IMF chief economist Olivier Blanchard describes a “two-speed recovery” around the globe, where emerging market countries like China and India are growing at a brisk clip of around 10%, and developed nations like the U.S. are lagging behind, with growth rates 3% and below. Stronger Eurozone states are struggling to prop up debt-laden Ireland and Greece. Blanchard hopes to avoid a larger European calamity by opening up the books of European banks to allay investors’ fears and help recapitalize the banks at appropriate levels.
The U.S. and China represent another hot spot for the IMF, with the U.S. running a vast current account deficit (due to years of high U.S. consumption and low household savings), and China a large current account surplus. Both nations want to reverse the situation, but their timetables differ radically. China fears increasing domestic consumption too rapidly and overheating its economy, so is thinking in terms of years. The U.S. wants faster action. If net exports do not improve in the U.S., says Blanchard, then it will be “confronted with a difficult choice: either it does fiscal consolidation, risking slowing growth, or continues large deficits…There are reasons to think one might want to worry.”
Emerging markets “have learned lessons from previous crises,” says Pedro Aspe, and are generally rebounding from the downturn. In Latin America, they have followed the lead of Chile, adopting an independent central bank, trade liberalization, pension reforms, and flexible labor markets. When they need a stimulus, they lower interest rates and keep public debt low. Aspe also raises red flags around debt and financing in the Eurozone: “You take more financing, and then the private sector knows this game well…They squeeze economies. Face the debt overhang fast.”
Robert Gordon replaces the word overhang “with a more evocative word: hangover.” The U.S. economy is still weighed down by consumer liabilities, although the household savings rate has improved. There remains an oversupply of residential housing and nonresidential structures, and continued unemployment, only to worsen as state and local governments shed more workers. “What do we do?” he asks repeatedly. “Monetary policy is out of steam.” On fiscal policy, Gordon says, “We have to pretend we’re a benevolent dictator and ignore political paralysis.” He recommends cutting corporate income tax, extending unemployment compensation and making food stamps more generous. He also endorses a new jobs tax credit, but admits it will be “hard to design.”
Paul Krugman confesses having “nightmares for about a decade before this thing actually happened.” What is “worse than he anticipated” is the “apparent inability of policy to come to grips with this.” Our paralysis has arrived in part because “we’ve run into the limits of Samuelsonian synthesis.” The traditional levers of monetary and fiscal policy to correct minor market failures have failed. The academic consensus around Keynesian economics has broken, making it less possible to “push through the strong policies you really need at a time like this.” This leaves an opening for people “who really believe government should keep its hands off,” who don’t believe in the need for monetary policy “to be adventurous and unconventional just to avoid utter catastrophe.”
In addition, “a prolonged period of financial stability” made people careless, leading to mountains of debt. The resulting financial crisis demands aggressive fiscal policies that are politically impossible. “If you’d asked me five years ago what would happen if the U.S. had unemployment in excess of 9% and every prospect of continued high unemployment levels, I’d have said there would be overwhelming political demand for government to do something. In fact there isn’t. We have had a near collapse of the idea that government can do anything about this.”
N. Gregory Mankiw describes how times of economic crisis periodically challenge macroeconomists’ consensus of how the business cycle works, and how to fix it when it breaks. In the past few years, “the rock has rolled back to the bottom of the hill.” Mankiw believes he and fellow macroeconomists “need to be humble” and “recognize there are a lot of things we don’t know.” For instance, the conventional take was that monetary policy was the main tool for dealing with recession: cut interest rates, stimulate borrowing and investment, increase aggregate demand. But today, the Fed cannot realistically lower its interest rate below zero. If he tried to increase target inflation rates, Ben Bernanke would “soon be former chairman,” says Mankiw, who finds the long-term fiscal picture “extremely worrisome.” The administration’s last budget “has debt to GDP ratio rising as far as the eye can see.” Without major reforms on entitlements and the tax code, there must be another revenue source, and Mankiw “is expecting a value added tax.”
“In my heart, I feel deeply that actions taken in the last two years were incredibly effective and played a role in the recovery we’re seeing,” says Christina Romer, a forceful advocate for such strong fiscal policy as the administration’s $787 billion stimulus package. Legislation passed during the recent lame duck session of Congress should help blunt the loss of stimulus money. Nevertheless, the “U.S. economy is still suffering from a tremendous shortfall of aggregate demand,” with factories and workers unoccupied. She worries that policymakers’ anxiety about the long-run fiscal deficit will prevent the kind of immediate measures “we desperately need,” that would jumpstart recovery. She argues for “high quality additional fiscal stimulus coupled with a signed, sealed and delivered agreement for deficit reduction starting in 2012 or 2013.” This agreement would tackle “the true driver of the deficit, long-run entitlement … spending on Social Security and Medicare,” and “must surely raise additional revenue.”
IMF chief economist Olivier Blanchard describes a “two-speed recovery” around the globe, where emerging market countries like China and India are growing at a brisk clip of around 10%, and developed nations like the U.S. are lagging behind, with growth rates 3% and below. Stronger Eurozone states are struggling to prop up debt-laden Ireland and Greece. Blanchard hopes to avoid a larger European calamity by opening up the books of European banks to allay investors’ fears and help recapitalize the banks at appropriate levels.
The U.S. and China represent another hot spot for the IMF, with the U.S. running a vast current account deficit (due to years of high U.S. consumption and low household savings), and China a large current account surplus. Both nations want to reverse the situation, but their timetables differ radically. China fears increasing domestic consumption too rapidly and overheating its economy, so is thinking in terms of years. The U.S. wants faster action. If net exports do not improve in the U.S., says Blanchard, then it will be “confronted with a difficult choice: either it does fiscal consolidation, risking slowing growth, or continues large deficits…There are reasons to think one might want to worry.”
Emerging markets “have learned lessons from previous crises,” says Pedro Aspe, and are generally rebounding from the downturn. In Latin America, they have followed the lead of Chile, adopting an independent central bank, trade liberalization, pension reforms, and flexible labor markets. When they need a stimulus, they lower interest rates and keep public debt low. Aspe also raises red flags around debt and financing in the Eurozone: “You take more financing, and then the private sector knows this game well…They squeeze economies. Face the debt overhang fast.”
Robert Gordon replaces the word overhang “with a more evocative word: hangover.” The U.S. economy is still weighed down by consumer liabilities, although the household savings rate has improved. There remains an oversupply of residential housing and nonresidential structures, and continued unemployment, only to worsen as state and local governments shed more workers. “What do we do?” he asks repeatedly. “Monetary policy is out of steam.” On fiscal policy, Gordon says, “We have to pretend we’re a benevolent dictator and ignore political paralysis.” He recommends cutting corporate income tax, extending unemployment compensation and making food stamps more generous. He also endorses a new jobs tax credit, but admits it will be “hard to design.”
Paul Krugman confesses having “nightmares for about a decade before this thing actually happened.” What is “worse than he anticipated” is the “apparent inability of policy to come to grips with this.” Our paralysis has arrived in part because “we’ve run into the limits of Samuelsonian synthesis.” The traditional levers of monetary and fiscal policy to correct minor market failures have failed. The academic consensus around Keynesian economics has broken, making it less possible to “push through the strong policies you really need at a time like this.” This leaves an opening for people “who really believe government should keep its hands off,” who don’t believe in the need for monetary policy “to be adventurous and unconventional just to avoid utter catastrophe.”
In addition, “a prolonged period of financial stability” made people careless, leading to mountains of debt. The resulting financial crisis demands aggressive fiscal policies that are politically impossible. “If you’d asked me five years ago what would happen if the U.S. had unemployment in excess of 9% and every prospect of continued high unemployment levels, I’d have said there would be overwhelming political demand for government to do something. In fact there isn’t. We have had a near collapse of the idea that government can do anything about this.”
N. Gregory Mankiw describes how times of economic crisis periodically challenge macroeconomists’ consensus of how the business cycle works, and how to fix it when it breaks. In the past few years, “the rock has rolled back to the bottom of the hill.” Mankiw believes he and fellow macroeconomists “need to be humble” and “recognize there are a lot of things we don’t know.” For instance, the conventional take was that monetary policy was the main tool for dealing with recession: cut interest rates, stimulate borrowing and investment, increase aggregate demand. But today, the Fed cannot realistically lower its interest rate below zero. If he tried to increase target inflation rates, Ben Bernanke would “soon be former chairman,” says Mankiw, who finds the long-term fiscal picture “extremely worrisome.” The administration’s last budget “has debt to GDP ratio rising as far as the eye can see.” Without major reforms on entitlements and the tax code, there must be another revenue source, and Mankiw “is expecting a value added tax.”
“In my heart, I feel deeply that actions taken in the last two years were incredibly effective and played a role in the recovery we’re seeing,” says Christina Romer, a forceful advocate for such strong fiscal policy as the administration’s $787 billion stimulus package. Legislation passed during the recent lame duck session of Congress should help blunt the loss of stimulus money. Nevertheless, the “U.S. economy is still suffering from a tremendous shortfall of aggregate demand,” with factories and workers unoccupied. She worries that policymakers’ anxiety about the long-run fiscal deficit will prevent the kind of immediate measures “we desperately need,” that would jumpstart recovery. She argues for “high quality additional fiscal stimulus coupled with a signed, sealed and delivered agreement for deficit reduction starting in 2012 or 2013.” This agreement would tackle “the true driver of the deficit, long-run entitlement … spending on Social Security and Medicare,” and “must surely raise additional revenue.”
Categories: TemeTV
The Evolution of Economic Science: Macroeconomics, Growth, and Development
This panel first looks inward, at the evolution of macroeconomics in the past century, and the emergence of microeconomic foundations in macroeconomics, then shifts outward, to the application of economic analysis to such issues as structural unemployment, the ongoing U.S. recession, and the best ways to help developing nations.
When he took his first economics course in 1940, Robert Solow tells us, “There was no such thing as macroeconomics.” The general framework for discussing large-scale fluctuations in economies , “born in Keynes’ general theory in 1936,” took a while to evolve. Keynes, says Solow, wanted a “macroeconomics that would keep closely in touch with data and with actual events.” From the 1950s through the 1970s, macroeconomics “was all Keynesian,” but there was “lots of room for ideology to be dragged in.” A sea change occurred in the late ‘70s, driven by stagflation. Macroeconomists could not explain the phenomenon, providing an opening “for opponents of this way of doing macroeconomics.” After the ‘70s, “paying close attention to events got to be a bad thing,” says Solow. Some economists declared it was time to erase the distinction between macro and microeconomics, but says Solow, “You can’t answer the questions macro has asked by modeling whole economies as the interaction of tens of millions of households, firms and products… It’s like trying to design an airplane molecule by molecule.”
Peter Diamond was part of a generation of researchers in the 1960s who hoped to construct a micro foundation to macroeconomics. In particular, he worked to incorporate into the basic general equilibrium model two Keynesian ideas that didn’t fit so comfortably: the significance of current income, and “the stickiness of wages.” Economists explored how the labor market functioned in the economy, and learned to model vast flows of workers moving in and out of employment. Analyzing such flows helps inform policy discussions about unemployment insurance, says Diamond. While these approaches have been incorporated into “otherwise conventional macro models,” he looks forward to “a big expansion of range of micro foundation models that will be consistent with the general equilibrium views of thinking about the whole economy, and Keynesian views … that we get events that really affect things.”
Robert Hall defends economists attacked for not predicting “the big slump.” Says Hall, “We did a lot of research that turned out to be highly material.” He boils down the financial crisis to such factors as deregulation of financial institutions, a massive build-up of consumer debt and the overshooting of housing prices. Financial fallout from the 2008 crisis continues today: credit card interest rates remain high, and available credit is extremely restricted, impeding recovery. The Federal Reserve’s hands are tied, because it can’t lower interest rates anymore; “the normal equilibrium process of the economy fails in a situation like this,” says Hall. Paradoxically, a little inflation would be good, because it might “get people to perceive that now is a great time to buy stuff instead of later.” Over the next four years, Hall believes unemployment will get back to normal, and households will work down accumulated debt. He frets that current legislation has “only scratched the surface” of correcting the regulatory lapses that triggered the crisis. Says Hall, “We need robust financial institutions with lots of capital.”
For years, people have debated the effectiveness of aid to developing nations. Development economics is trying “to move away from big questions…to smaller questions for which we might possibly have the answer,” says Esther Duflo. She studies the economics of public health aid in poor countries, where diseases like malaria are responsible for millions of deaths. Even where the benefits of aid are clear, there are still “heated arguments, ideology and passion.” Studies by Duflo and her colleagues have largely quieted concerns that people offered free health services such as bed nets for malaria, or immunizations, decline them, or after receiving them, refuse to purchase subsidized healthcare in the future. This research is changing policies: Kenya has begun distributing bed nets for free, for instance. Small investments in health pay large dividends. Duflo cites a study that school children who are de-wormed for a year longer than their peers earn 20% more each year when they are adults. “A patient step-by-step approach is a productive way of trying to understand how the poor behave … and how we can possibly help them get out of poverty traps.”
When he took his first economics course in 1940, Robert Solow tells us, “There was no such thing as macroeconomics.” The general framework for discussing large-scale fluctuations in economies , “born in Keynes’ general theory in 1936,” took a while to evolve. Keynes, says Solow, wanted a “macroeconomics that would keep closely in touch with data and with actual events.” From the 1950s through the 1970s, macroeconomics “was all Keynesian,” but there was “lots of room for ideology to be dragged in.” A sea change occurred in the late ‘70s, driven by stagflation. Macroeconomists could not explain the phenomenon, providing an opening “for opponents of this way of doing macroeconomics.” After the ‘70s, “paying close attention to events got to be a bad thing,” says Solow. Some economists declared it was time to erase the distinction between macro and microeconomics, but says Solow, “You can’t answer the questions macro has asked by modeling whole economies as the interaction of tens of millions of households, firms and products… It’s like trying to design an airplane molecule by molecule.”
Peter Diamond was part of a generation of researchers in the 1960s who hoped to construct a micro foundation to macroeconomics. In particular, he worked to incorporate into the basic general equilibrium model two Keynesian ideas that didn’t fit so comfortably: the significance of current income, and “the stickiness of wages.” Economists explored how the labor market functioned in the economy, and learned to model vast flows of workers moving in and out of employment. Analyzing such flows helps inform policy discussions about unemployment insurance, says Diamond. While these approaches have been incorporated into “otherwise conventional macro models,” he looks forward to “a big expansion of range of micro foundation models that will be consistent with the general equilibrium views of thinking about the whole economy, and Keynesian views … that we get events that really affect things.”
Robert Hall defends economists attacked for not predicting “the big slump.” Says Hall, “We did a lot of research that turned out to be highly material.” He boils down the financial crisis to such factors as deregulation of financial institutions, a massive build-up of consumer debt and the overshooting of housing prices. Financial fallout from the 2008 crisis continues today: credit card interest rates remain high, and available credit is extremely restricted, impeding recovery. The Federal Reserve’s hands are tied, because it can’t lower interest rates anymore; “the normal equilibrium process of the economy fails in a situation like this,” says Hall. Paradoxically, a little inflation would be good, because it might “get people to perceive that now is a great time to buy stuff instead of later.” Over the next four years, Hall believes unemployment will get back to normal, and households will work down accumulated debt. He frets that current legislation has “only scratched the surface” of correcting the regulatory lapses that triggered the crisis. Says Hall, “We need robust financial institutions with lots of capital.”
For years, people have debated the effectiveness of aid to developing nations. Development economics is trying “to move away from big questions…to smaller questions for which we might possibly have the answer,” says Esther Duflo. She studies the economics of public health aid in poor countries, where diseases like malaria are responsible for millions of deaths. Even where the benefits of aid are clear, there are still “heated arguments, ideology and passion.” Studies by Duflo and her colleagues have largely quieted concerns that people offered free health services such as bed nets for malaria, or immunizations, decline them, or after receiving them, refuse to purchase subsidized healthcare in the future. This research is changing policies: Kenya has begun distributing bed nets for free, for instance. Small investments in health pay large dividends. Duflo cites a study that school children who are de-wormed for a year longer than their peers earn 20% more each year when they are adults. “A patient step-by-step approach is a productive way of trying to understand how the poor behave … and how we can possibly help them get out of poverty traps.”
Categories: TemeTV
<img vspace="4" hspace="4" border="1"
Categories: TemeTV
The Evolution of Economic Science: Individual and Firm Behavior
The astonishing contributions MIT has made to the world of economics emerged from “a melting pot of analytical tools and mathematical methods, mixed with a healthy interest in real world questions, grounded in real world problems,” says James Poterba, crystallizing many of the themes of the symposium, and its inaugural session. As they discuss the evolution of the profession and their own work, a distinguished group of economists also attest to MIT’s unique role as a place of research, teaching, and influence in the larger world.
“Without the right economics, we will get the wrong economic policy,” says George Akerlof, who finds fault with some “norms of economic thinking,” including the very way economists attack a problem, and publish in journals. Akerlof describes how John Maynard Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money was boiled down “to three easy equations” that became the basis for all macroeconomic models today. This reduction “spawned a great tragedy for which today we’re paying a great price,” because it did not address Keynes’ concern about irrational exuberance, “which explains why we get booms and busts, especially the sort that lead to economic calamities.” Akerlof worries that his profession may have evolved with certain biases and lacks the “empirical checks” to ensure “an economics that really serves the public.”
Avinash Dixit credits not just “stellar teachers” but fellow MIT students at “Friday lunchtime bridge games” for his economics education. He celebrates in particular MIT’s style of economic modeling, which he characterizes as not just “frontier research,” but an “art.” The MIT approach distills a central question, discarding all else to drill into specifics. Dixit holds up
Paul Samuelson’s Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest, which addressed the problem of overlapping generations working and saving, and retiring and spending their savings. MIT protégées built on Samuelson’s insights. Dixit invokes for instance
Peter Diamond’s Model of National Debt -- “an absurdly simple model of complex reality, but its very simplicity allowed us to understand the key economic mechanisms at work.” While “some economists from other research styles dismiss these as ‘toy models,’” says Dixit, “these practitioners of the MIT style wear that label proudly.”
Microeconometrics has had a big impact on economic policy and in people’s lives, Jerry Hausman says, gathering and analyzing data on large numbers of people over significant periods of time, in such areas as consumer behavior and work life. The field can usefully pursue slippery questions of equilibrium, the push-pull of cause, effect and feedbacks among different economic variables. For instance, data describing the relation between individuals’ education and their earnings can be fed into a regression model that demonstrates a powerful positive coefficient – strong evidence of the “returns” to education. Hausman cites as well his research that persuaded cellphone companies they would profit more over time by subsidizing the price of phones and selling people long-term contracts.
Note: Paul L. Joskow begins, reading the remarks of Oliver Williamson, who was detained by weather. Joskow also provides commentary on Williamson’s remarks.
Although Oliver Williamson took no economics courses while earning his undergraduate degree at MIT, he learned an important lesson: engineering and economics differ as they move from theory to applications. While both fields assumed an absence of frictions in theory, engineers developed applications and models that made provision for friction, and economists maintained the illusion of perfection. Williamson deployed this insight to develop his theory of transaction cost economics. He notes, “My engineering training provided grounding that made it easy for me…to recognize all feasible forms of organizations are flawed in relation to a hypothetical ideal.” To understand real world organizations and relationships, it was important to detect imperfections, and build them into the models. “Transaction cost economics gave us a framework to understand phenomena such as vertical integration, vertical market restrictions, long-term contracts, regulation, deregulation, the use of debt and equity and so on that thereafter provided a basis for shaping public policy toward business.”
“Without the right economics, we will get the wrong economic policy,” says George Akerlof, who finds fault with some “norms of economic thinking,” including the very way economists attack a problem, and publish in journals. Akerlof describes how John Maynard Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money was boiled down “to three easy equations” that became the basis for all macroeconomic models today. This reduction “spawned a great tragedy for which today we’re paying a great price,” because it did not address Keynes’ concern about irrational exuberance, “which explains why we get booms and busts, especially the sort that lead to economic calamities.” Akerlof worries that his profession may have evolved with certain biases and lacks the “empirical checks” to ensure “an economics that really serves the public.”
Avinash Dixit credits not just “stellar teachers” but fellow MIT students at “Friday lunchtime bridge games” for his economics education. He celebrates in particular MIT’s style of economic modeling, which he characterizes as not just “frontier research,” but an “art.” The MIT approach distills a central question, discarding all else to drill into specifics. Dixit holds up
Paul Samuelson’s Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest, which addressed the problem of overlapping generations working and saving, and retiring and spending their savings. MIT protégées built on Samuelson’s insights. Dixit invokes for instance
Peter Diamond’s Model of National Debt -- “an absurdly simple model of complex reality, but its very simplicity allowed us to understand the key economic mechanisms at work.” While “some economists from other research styles dismiss these as ‘toy models,’” says Dixit, “these practitioners of the MIT style wear that label proudly.”
Microeconometrics has had a big impact on economic policy and in people’s lives, Jerry Hausman says, gathering and analyzing data on large numbers of people over significant periods of time, in such areas as consumer behavior and work life. The field can usefully pursue slippery questions of equilibrium, the push-pull of cause, effect and feedbacks among different economic variables. For instance, data describing the relation between individuals’ education and their earnings can be fed into a regression model that demonstrates a powerful positive coefficient – strong evidence of the “returns” to education. Hausman cites as well his research that persuaded cellphone companies they would profit more over time by subsidizing the price of phones and selling people long-term contracts.
Note: Paul L. Joskow begins, reading the remarks of Oliver Williamson, who was detained by weather. Joskow also provides commentary on Williamson’s remarks.
Although Oliver Williamson took no economics courses while earning his undergraduate degree at MIT, he learned an important lesson: engineering and economics differ as they move from theory to applications. While both fields assumed an absence of frictions in theory, engineers developed applications and models that made provision for friction, and economists maintained the illusion of perfection. Williamson deployed this insight to develop his theory of transaction cost economics. He notes, “My engineering training provided grounding that made it easy for me…to recognize all feasible forms of organizations are flawed in relation to a hypothetical ideal.” To understand real world organizations and relationships, it was important to detect imperfections, and build them into the models. “Transaction cost economics gave us a framework to understand phenomena such as vertical integration, vertical market restrictions, long-term contracts, regulation, deregulation, the use of debt and equity and so on that thereafter provided a basis for shaping public policy toward business.”
Categories: TemeTV
Perceptive Mobile Robots Working Safely Alongside Humans
Although we are still far from the moment of singularity, or even Star Wars ‘droids, we can anticipate robot colleagues in the near future, believes Seth Teller. He is developing ‘situationally aware’ machines to help out humans in those “unstructured environments…where we live, work and recreate.”
Teller’s goal is not “to solve the full AI problem,” but to provide robot solutions to specific challenges. Whatever the project, the robot must successfully navigate a messy human world with appropriate sensor data, and interact with us on our terms, through speech and gestures, overcoming potential unease. “We are working with ways of creating natural interactions between humans and robots, paying attention to notions of human acceptance,” says Teller.
The first venture Teller describes is an unmanned car, developed for a DARPA competition. Teller’s team had to design a vehicle that could not only “see” around itself, but understand the rules and hazards urban driving. Teller shows video of the “Urban Challenge” finals, with his car waiting patiently at an intersection for another car to pull out –“no honking or obscenities,” he notes. Someday, believes Teller, such a vehicle could help reduce U.S. driving fatalities, improve gas mileage and human productivity, and even replace thousands of military ground vehicles.
Teller has also been applying the principles of autonomous mobility to logistics in the form of an unmanned forklift for the military. Typical robotic forklifts function in indoor warehouses with smooth floors, uniform lighting, precise maps. Teller’s challenge was to come up with a device the “military could set down in a patch of earth somewhere.” This forklift robot is equipped not just with laser scanners to detect fixed or moving obstacles, but microphones, so it can stop if it hears a command or shouting. It also displays “text strings and color kinetic LEDs” to let people know where it is going.
Teller is applying this kind of machine intelligence to aid severely disabled people, with a motorized wheelchair that lets users navigate around an institutional setting, learning to map a space using verbal labels from a human trainer. A related assistive technology may offer blind people the possibility of greater independence and efficiency. Teller imagines a device that can “build up a persistent model of the wearer’s surround,” which could let a blind person know where she left her keys, or send out spoken or braille navigational instructions. Together, these projects point toward machine minds that can increasingly interpret human commands and needs, achieving “validation” from human supervisors and Teller hopes, “a gradual path toward autonomy.”
Teller’s goal is not “to solve the full AI problem,” but to provide robot solutions to specific challenges. Whatever the project, the robot must successfully navigate a messy human world with appropriate sensor data, and interact with us on our terms, through speech and gestures, overcoming potential unease. “We are working with ways of creating natural interactions between humans and robots, paying attention to notions of human acceptance,” says Teller.
The first venture Teller describes is an unmanned car, developed for a DARPA competition. Teller’s team had to design a vehicle that could not only “see” around itself, but understand the rules and hazards urban driving. Teller shows video of the “Urban Challenge” finals, with his car waiting patiently at an intersection for another car to pull out –“no honking or obscenities,” he notes. Someday, believes Teller, such a vehicle could help reduce U.S. driving fatalities, improve gas mileage and human productivity, and even replace thousands of military ground vehicles.
Teller has also been applying the principles of autonomous mobility to logistics in the form of an unmanned forklift for the military. Typical robotic forklifts function in indoor warehouses with smooth floors, uniform lighting, precise maps. Teller’s challenge was to come up with a device the “military could set down in a patch of earth somewhere.” This forklift robot is equipped not just with laser scanners to detect fixed or moving obstacles, but microphones, so it can stop if it hears a command or shouting. It also displays “text strings and color kinetic LEDs” to let people know where it is going.
Teller is applying this kind of machine intelligence to aid severely disabled people, with a motorized wheelchair that lets users navigate around an institutional setting, learning to map a space using verbal labels from a human trainer. A related assistive technology may offer blind people the possibility of greater independence and efficiency. Teller imagines a device that can “build up a persistent model of the wearer’s surround,” which could let a blind person know where she left her keys, or send out spoken or braille navigational instructions. Together, these projects point toward machine minds that can increasingly interpret human commands and needs, achieving “validation” from human supervisors and Teller hopes, “a gradual path toward autonomy.”
Categories: TemeTV
Perceptive Mobile Robots Working Safely Alongside Humans
Although we are still far from the moment of singularity, or even Star Wars ‘droids, we can anticipate robot colleagues in the near future, believes Seth Teller. He is developing ‘situationally aware’ machines to help out humans in those “unstructured environments…where we live, work and recreate.”
Teller’s goal is not “to solve the full AI problem,” but to provide robot solutions to specific challenges. Whatever the project, the robot must successfully navigate a messy human world with appropriate sensor data, and interact with us on our terms, through speech and gestures, overcoming potential unease. “We are working with ways of creating natural interactions between humans and robots, paying attention to notions of human acceptance,” says Teller.
The first venture Teller describes is an unmanned car, developed for a DARPA competition. Teller’s team had to design a vehicle that could not only “see” around itself, but understand the rules and hazards urban driving. Teller shows video of the “Urban Challenge” finals, with his car waiting patiently at an intersection for another car to pull out –“no honking or obscenities,” he notes. Someday, believes Teller, such a vehicle could help reduce U.S. driving fatalities, improve gas mileage and human productivity, and even replace thousands of military ground vehicles.
Teller has also been applying the principles of autonomous mobility to logistics in the form of an unmanned forklift for the military. Typical robotic forklifts function in indoor warehouses with smooth floors, uniform lighting, precise maps. Teller’s challenge was to come up with a device the “military could set down in a patch of earth somewhere.” This forklift robot is equipped not just with laser scanners to detect fixed or moving obstacles, but microphones, so it can stop if it hears a command or shouting. It also displays “text strings and color kinetic LEDs” to let people know where it is going.
Teller is applying this kind of machine intelligence to aid severely disabled people, with a motorized wheelchair that lets users navigate around an institutional setting, learning to map a space using verbal labels from a human trainer. A related assistive technology may offer blind people the possibility of greater independence and efficiency. Teller imagines a device that can “build up a persistent model of the wearer’s surround,” which could let a blind person know where she left her keys, or send out spoken or braille navigational instructions. Together, these projects point toward machine minds that can increasingly interpret human commands and needs, achieving “validation” from human supervisors and Teller hopes, “a gradual path toward autonomy.”
Teller’s goal is not “to solve the full AI problem,” but to provide robot solutions to specific challenges. Whatever the project, the robot must successfully navigate a messy human world with appropriate sensor data, and interact with us on our terms, through speech and gestures, overcoming potential unease. “We are working with ways of creating natural interactions between humans and robots, paying attention to notions of human acceptance,” says Teller.
The first venture Teller describes is an unmanned car, developed for a DARPA competition. Teller’s team had to design a vehicle that could not only “see” around itself, but understand the rules and hazards urban driving. Teller shows video of the “Urban Challenge” finals, with his car waiting patiently at an intersection for another car to pull out –“no honking or obscenities,” he notes. Someday, believes Teller, such a vehicle could help reduce U.S. driving fatalities, improve gas mileage and human productivity, and even replace thousands of military ground vehicles.
Teller has also been applying the principles of autonomous mobility to logistics in the form of an unmanned forklift for the military. Typical robotic forklifts function in indoor warehouses with smooth floors, uniform lighting, precise maps. Teller’s challenge was to come up with a device the “military could set down in a patch of earth somewhere.” This forklift robot is equipped not just with laser scanners to detect fixed or moving obstacles, but microphones, so it can stop if it hears a command or shouting. It also displays “text strings and color kinetic LEDs” to let people know where it is going.
Teller is applying this kind of machine intelligence to aid severely disabled people, with a motorized wheelchair that lets users navigate around an institutional setting, learning to map a space using verbal labels from a human trainer. A related assistive technology may offer blind people the possibility of greater independence and efficiency. Teller imagines a device that can “build up a persistent model of the wearer’s surround,” which could let a blind person know where she left her keys, or send out spoken or braille navigational instructions. Together, these projects point toward machine minds that can increasingly interpret human commands and needs, achieving “validation” from human supervisors and Teller hopes, “a gradual path toward autonomy.”
Categories: TemeTV
Mathematics, Common Sense, and Good Luck: My Life and Careers
Don’t expect to glean any market tips or trading secrets from James Simons, who steadfastly refuses to disclose the method behind his remarkable record in investing. Instead, listen to this mathematician, hedge fund manager and philanthropist sum up a remarkably varied and rich career, and offer some “guiding principles” distilled along the way.
Simons drew a bead on studying math at MIT from an early age, which some acquaintances found surprising. As a 14-year-old, he was demoted in a temporary job from stockroom worker to floor-sweeper, because he “couldn’t remember where in hell everything went.” This switch suited him fine, since he had “lots of time to think.” When he told his employers he hoped to attend MIT, “they thought it was the funniest thing.” Ultimately, Simons had no choice about it: After Wesleyan recruited, then rejected him, there was only MIT. “I was destined for this place,” he says.
The idea of a math career was “clinched” for Simons after a typical late night of poker and sandwiches with MIT classmates. At 1 a.m. in a Brookline restaurant, Simons saw MIT math legends Isadore Singer and Warren Ambrose “doing math over coffee and cigarettes,” which he “thought was the coolest thing.” After a motor scooter trip to Bogota with Colombian friends -- in whose business he fatefully invested -- Simons leapt into the math phase of his career, writing a famous Ph.D. thesis, teaching at MIT, solving prickly geometry problems and helping build bridges between math and physics. During this phase, he managed to get fired as a cryptanalyst at a Defense Department think tank, after criticizing the pro-Vietnam War stance of his boss, General Maxwell Taylor.
While at Stony Brook’s math department, Simons “got really stuck, very frustrated,” trying “to prove a certain number was irrational.” Meanwhile, he had begun investing dividends generated by his South American business venture and “found out I was not bad at it.” In 1978 at age 38, with 20 years behind him as a mathematician, he concluded it was time for a change. He began an investment business, Renaissance Technologies, that deployed sophisticated, proprietary models to generate astonishing returns (and business envy) over many years. “We have a lot of smart guys,” he comments.
After his retirement in 2009, Simons got “busy as hell” with his third career. The Simons Foundation supports basic math and physics as well as autism research. Simons also wants to improve math at the high school level, by pumping money into teaching jobs so talented people don’t drift to “Google or Goldman Sachs.”
Simons says he is “always doing something new,” and doesn’t like to run with the pack. This approach, which he recommends, “gives you a chance.” Some other parting tips: collaborate with the best people you possibly can; try at problems “for a hell of a long time;” be guided by beauty; and “hope for some good luck.”
Simons drew a bead on studying math at MIT from an early age, which some acquaintances found surprising. As a 14-year-old, he was demoted in a temporary job from stockroom worker to floor-sweeper, because he “couldn’t remember where in hell everything went.” This switch suited him fine, since he had “lots of time to think.” When he told his employers he hoped to attend MIT, “they thought it was the funniest thing.” Ultimately, Simons had no choice about it: After Wesleyan recruited, then rejected him, there was only MIT. “I was destined for this place,” he says.
The idea of a math career was “clinched” for Simons after a typical late night of poker and sandwiches with MIT classmates. At 1 a.m. in a Brookline restaurant, Simons saw MIT math legends Isadore Singer and Warren Ambrose “doing math over coffee and cigarettes,” which he “thought was the coolest thing.” After a motor scooter trip to Bogota with Colombian friends -- in whose business he fatefully invested -- Simons leapt into the math phase of his career, writing a famous Ph.D. thesis, teaching at MIT, solving prickly geometry problems and helping build bridges between math and physics. During this phase, he managed to get fired as a cryptanalyst at a Defense Department think tank, after criticizing the pro-Vietnam War stance of his boss, General Maxwell Taylor.
While at Stony Brook’s math department, Simons “got really stuck, very frustrated,” trying “to prove a certain number was irrational.” Meanwhile, he had begun investing dividends generated by his South American business venture and “found out I was not bad at it.” In 1978 at age 38, with 20 years behind him as a mathematician, he concluded it was time for a change. He began an investment business, Renaissance Technologies, that deployed sophisticated, proprietary models to generate astonishing returns (and business envy) over many years. “We have a lot of smart guys,” he comments.
After his retirement in 2009, Simons got “busy as hell” with his third career. The Simons Foundation supports basic math and physics as well as autism research. Simons also wants to improve math at the high school level, by pumping money into teaching jobs so talented people don’t drift to “Google or Goldman Sachs.”
Simons says he is “always doing something new,” and doesn’t like to run with the pack. This approach, which he recommends, “gives you a chance.” Some other parting tips: collaborate with the best people you possibly can; try at problems “for a hell of a long time;” be guided by beauty; and “hope for some good luck.”
Categories: TemeTV
Mathematics, Common Sense, and Good Luck: My Life and Careers
Don’t expect to glean any market tips or trading secrets from James Simons, who steadfastly refuses to disclose the method behind his remarkable record in investing. Instead, listen to this mathematician, hedge fund manager and philanthropist sum up a remarkably varied and rich career, and offer some “guiding principles” distilled along the way.
Simons drew a bead on studying math at MIT from an early age, which some acquaintances found surprising. As a 14-year-old, he was demoted in a temporary job from stockroom worker to floor-sweeper, because he “couldn’t remember where in hell everything went.” This switch suited him fine, since he had “lots of time to think.” When he told his employers he hoped to attend MIT, “they thought it was the funniest thing.” Ultimately, Simons had no choice about it: After Wesleyan recruited, then rejected him, there was only MIT. “I was destined for this place,” he says.
The idea of a math career was “clinched” for Simons after a typical late night of poker and sandwiches with MIT classmates. At 1 a.m. in a Brookline restaurant, Simons saw MIT math legends Isadore Singer and Warren Ambrose “doing math over coffee and cigarettes,” which he “thought was the coolest thing.” After a motor scooter trip to Bogota with Colombian friends -- in whose business he fatefully invested -- Simons leapt into the math phase of his career, writing a famous Ph.D. thesis, teaching at MIT, solving prickly geometry problems and helping build bridges between math and physics. During this phase, he managed to get fired as a cryptanalyst at a Defense Department think tank, after criticizing the pro-Vietnam War stance of his boss, General Maxwell Taylor.
While at Stony Brook’s math department, Simons “got really stuck, very frustrated,” trying “to prove a certain number was irrational.” Meanwhile, he had begun investing dividends generated by his South American business venture and “found out I was not bad at it.” In 1978 at age 38, with 20 years behind him as a mathematician, he concluded it was time for a change. He began an investment business, Renaissance Technologies, that deployed sophisticated, proprietary models to generate astonishing returns (and business envy) over many years. “We have a lot of smart guys,” he comments.
After his retirement in 2009, Simons got “busy as hell” with his third career. The Simons Foundation supports basic math and physics as well as autism research. Simons also wants to improve math at the high school level, by pumping money into teaching jobs so talented people don’t drift to “Google or Goldman Sachs.”
Simons says he is “always doing something new,” and doesn’t like to run with the pack. This approach, which he recommends, “gives you a chance.” Some other parting tips: collaborate with the best people you possibly can; try at problems “for a hell of a long time;” be guided by beauty; and “hope for some good luck.”
Simons drew a bead on studying math at MIT from an early age, which some acquaintances found surprising. As a 14-year-old, he was demoted in a temporary job from stockroom worker to floor-sweeper, because he “couldn’t remember where in hell everything went.” This switch suited him fine, since he had “lots of time to think.” When he told his employers he hoped to attend MIT, “they thought it was the funniest thing.” Ultimately, Simons had no choice about it: After Wesleyan recruited, then rejected him, there was only MIT. “I was destined for this place,” he says.
The idea of a math career was “clinched” for Simons after a typical late night of poker and sandwiches with MIT classmates. At 1 a.m. in a Brookline restaurant, Simons saw MIT math legends Isadore Singer and Warren Ambrose “doing math over coffee and cigarettes,” which he “thought was the coolest thing.” After a motor scooter trip to Bogota with Colombian friends -- in whose business he fatefully invested -- Simons leapt into the math phase of his career, writing a famous Ph.D. thesis, teaching at MIT, solving prickly geometry problems and helping build bridges between math and physics. During this phase, he managed to get fired as a cryptanalyst at a Defense Department think tank, after criticizing the pro-Vietnam War stance of his boss, General Maxwell Taylor.
While at Stony Brook’s math department, Simons “got really stuck, very frustrated,” trying “to prove a certain number was irrational.” Meanwhile, he had begun investing dividends generated by his South American business venture and “found out I was not bad at it.” In 1978 at age 38, with 20 years behind him as a mathematician, he concluded it was time for a change. He began an investment business, Renaissance Technologies, that deployed sophisticated, proprietary models to generate astonishing returns (and business envy) over many years. “We have a lot of smart guys,” he comments.
After his retirement in 2009, Simons got “busy as hell” with his third career. The Simons Foundation supports basic math and physics as well as autism research. Simons also wants to improve math at the high school level, by pumping money into teaching jobs so talented people don’t drift to “Google or Goldman Sachs.”
Simons says he is “always doing something new,” and doesn’t like to run with the pack. This approach, which he recommends, “gives you a chance.” Some other parting tips: collaborate with the best people you possibly can; try at problems “for a hell of a long time;” be guided by beauty; and “hope for some good luck.”
Categories: TemeTV
Communications in Slow-Moving Crises
What’s a journalist to do when a major story must be coaxed reluctantly into public view, or emerges on what seems like a geological time scale? These panelists discuss how to approach slowly evolving but urgent stories at a time when news coverage has shifted inexorably from print and its variable deadlines to the constant, repetitive churn of cable news and instant internet information. In setting up the discussion, moderator Thomas Levenson discusses the concept of “slow-moving crises” and changes in the practice of journalism.
Rosalind Williams situates the challenge facing journalism within the context of much greater historical change. She first finds a telling contradiction in the phrase “slow-moving crisis,” since the concept of crisis involves a “decisive stage…where change for better or worse happens.” For Williams, the lack of adequate terminology suggests that “something is happening in the world that hasn’t happened before...”
Classical historians regarded history as taking place “on a very stable stage of the world.” In the 19th century, that world began to speed up, and historians began to grapple with human actions and deeds that accelerated change in the world from centuries to decades. Yet, says Williams, “history appears to be slowing down, getting like molasses,” as events erupt, apparently conclude, then continue indefinitely. She cites the oil spill and the financial crisis as example of such “aftermaths.”
Paradoxically, “things are happening much faster and much slower,” she continues, because the “density of human presence on the planet speeds up environmental change and slows down political change,” creating a “viscosity” that makes history “work differently.” Journalists must take account of this transformation, and remember that “what is making things different is human dominance as never before.”
At the investigative journalism website ProPublica, Abrahm Lustgarten and his colleagues enjoy the unusual luxury of creative, long-term reporting projects. Their freedom to spend literally years working a topic can lead to identifying a crisis before anyone else -- such as the dangers of drilling for natural gas -- and often involves looking behind the headlines of a major story to uncover all-important context.
Lustgarten describes ProPublica’s take on the Gulf oil spill, which “worked around the perimeter of what was happening,” focusing on BP’s drilling record, and inadequate government regulation. Since their story “was somewhat less sexy,” they offered “narrative focus and depth to engage readers.” ProPublica made its story urgent through a “drumbeat of communication…a steady stream of provocative and revealing stories,” and a longer-form investigative piece. Lustgarten sees the story now “probably at its most critical stage, months after the spill,” with mainstream “coverage at a virtual standstill.”
Andrea Pitzer believes in the power of narrative to help people understand public crises and public policy issues, but worries that “using storytelling in long-term crisis coverage” carries some risks. Journalists who target “established authorities” with stories may be viewed as “trying to sell something.” She advocates “tilting more heavily toward stories with teeth for an audience that already understands the basic problem.”
Pitzer embraces diverse media approaches to boost “game-changing narratives.” Visuals such as the photos from Abu Ghraib can have an instant impact on public opinion. She describes innovative websites such as TBD, which uses the Storify social media tool to aggregate perspectives on an event, “creating a moment by moment breakdown.” Statistics come alive and marry to stories with new forms of data visualization. Pitzer encourages reaching out to ordinary people and giving them a stake in their own narratives, demonstrating “where they fit into the larger arc.” Says Pitzer, “If we’re better at storytelling and giving them hooks … we’ll be presenting information so people really understand their choices.”
Rosalind Williams situates the challenge facing journalism within the context of much greater historical change. She first finds a telling contradiction in the phrase “slow-moving crisis,” since the concept of crisis involves a “decisive stage…where change for better or worse happens.” For Williams, the lack of adequate terminology suggests that “something is happening in the world that hasn’t happened before...”
Classical historians regarded history as taking place “on a very stable stage of the world.” In the 19th century, that world began to speed up, and historians began to grapple with human actions and deeds that accelerated change in the world from centuries to decades. Yet, says Williams, “history appears to be slowing down, getting like molasses,” as events erupt, apparently conclude, then continue indefinitely. She cites the oil spill and the financial crisis as example of such “aftermaths.”
Paradoxically, “things are happening much faster and much slower,” she continues, because the “density of human presence on the planet speeds up environmental change and slows down political change,” creating a “viscosity” that makes history “work differently.” Journalists must take account of this transformation, and remember that “what is making things different is human dominance as never before.”
At the investigative journalism website ProPublica, Abrahm Lustgarten and his colleagues enjoy the unusual luxury of creative, long-term reporting projects. Their freedom to spend literally years working a topic can lead to identifying a crisis before anyone else -- such as the dangers of drilling for natural gas -- and often involves looking behind the headlines of a major story to uncover all-important context.
Lustgarten describes ProPublica’s take on the Gulf oil spill, which “worked around the perimeter of what was happening,” focusing on BP’s drilling record, and inadequate government regulation. Since their story “was somewhat less sexy,” they offered “narrative focus and depth to engage readers.” ProPublica made its story urgent through a “drumbeat of communication…a steady stream of provocative and revealing stories,” and a longer-form investigative piece. Lustgarten sees the story now “probably at its most critical stage, months after the spill,” with mainstream “coverage at a virtual standstill.”
Andrea Pitzer believes in the power of narrative to help people understand public crises and public policy issues, but worries that “using storytelling in long-term crisis coverage” carries some risks. Journalists who target “established authorities” with stories may be viewed as “trying to sell something.” She advocates “tilting more heavily toward stories with teeth for an audience that already understands the basic problem.”
Pitzer embraces diverse media approaches to boost “game-changing narratives.” Visuals such as the photos from Abu Ghraib can have an instant impact on public opinion. She describes innovative websites such as TBD, which uses the Storify social media tool to aggregate perspectives on an event, “creating a moment by moment breakdown.” Statistics come alive and marry to stories with new forms of data visualization. Pitzer encourages reaching out to ordinary people and giving them a stake in their own narratives, demonstrating “where they fit into the larger arc.” Says Pitzer, “If we’re better at storytelling and giving them hooks … we’ll be presenting information so people really understand their choices.”
Categories: TemeTV
Communications in Slow-Moving Crises
What’s a journalist to do when a major story must be coaxed reluctantly into public view, or emerges on what seems like a geological time scale? These panelists discuss how to approach slowly evolving but urgent stories at a time when news coverage has shifted inexorably from print and its variable deadlines to the constant, repetitive churn of cable news and instant internet information. In setting up the discussion, moderator Thomas Levenson discusses the concept of “slow-moving crises” and changes in the practice of journalism.
Rosalind Williams situates the challenge facing journalism within the context of much greater historical change. She first finds a telling contradiction in the phrase “slow-moving crisis,” since the concept of crisis involves a “decisive stage…where change for better or worse happens.” For Williams, the lack of adequate terminology suggests that “something is happening in the world that hasn’t happened before...”
Classical historians regarded history as taking place “on a very stable stage of the world.” In the 19th century, that world began to speed up, and historians began to grapple with human actions and deeds that accelerated change in the world from centuries to decades. Yet, says Williams, “history appears to be slowing down, getting like molasses,” as events erupt, apparently conclude, then continue indefinitely. She cites the oil spill and the financial crisis as example of such “aftermaths.”
Paradoxically, “things are happening much faster and much slower,” she continues, because the “density of human presence on the planet speeds up environmental change and slows down political change,” creating a “viscosity” that makes history “work differently.” Journalists must take account of this transformation, and remember that “what is making things different is human dominance as never before.”
At the investigative journalism website ProPublica, Abrahm Lustgarten and his colleagues enjoy the unusual luxury of creative, long-term reporting projects. Their freedom to spend literally years working a topic can lead to identifying a crisis before anyone else -- such as the dangers of drilling for natural gas -- and often involves looking behind the headlines of a major story to uncover all-important context.
Lustgarten describes ProPublica’s take on the Gulf oil spill, which “worked around the perimeter of what was happening,” focusing on BP’s drilling record, and inadequate government regulation. Since their story “was somewhat less sexy,” they offered “narrative focus and depth to engage readers.” ProPublica made its story urgent through a “drumbeat of communication…a steady stream of provocative and revealing stories,” and a longer-form investigative piece. Lustgarten sees the story now “probably at its most critical stage, months after the spill,” with mainstream “coverage at a virtual standstill.”
Andrea Pitzer believes in the power of narrative to help people understand public crises and public policy issues, but worries that “using storytelling in long-term crisis coverage” carries some risks. Journalists who target “established authorities” with stories may be viewed as “trying to sell something.” She advocates “tilting more heavily toward stories with teeth for an audience that already understands the basic problem.”
Pitzer embraces diverse media approaches to boost “game-changing narratives.” Visuals such as the photos from Abu Ghraib can have an instant impact on public opinion. She describes innovative websites such as TBD, which uses the Storify social media tool to aggregate perspectives on an event, “creating a moment by moment breakdown.” Statistics come alive and marry to stories with new forms of data visualization. Pitzer encourages reaching out to ordinary people and giving them a stake in their own narratives, demonstrating “where they fit into the larger arc.” Says Pitzer, “If we’re better at storytelling and giving them hooks … we’ll be presenting information so people really understand their choices.”
Rosalind Williams situates the challenge facing journalism within the context of much greater historical change. She first finds a telling contradiction in the phrase “slow-moving crisis,” since the concept of crisis involves a “decisive stage…where change for better or worse happens.” For Williams, the lack of adequate terminology suggests that “something is happening in the world that hasn’t happened before...”
Classical historians regarded history as taking place “on a very stable stage of the world.” In the 19th century, that world began to speed up, and historians began to grapple with human actions and deeds that accelerated change in the world from centuries to decades. Yet, says Williams, “history appears to be slowing down, getting like molasses,” as events erupt, apparently conclude, then continue indefinitely. She cites the oil spill and the financial crisis as example of such “aftermaths.”
Paradoxically, “things are happening much faster and much slower,” she continues, because the “density of human presence on the planet speeds up environmental change and slows down political change,” creating a “viscosity” that makes history “work differently.” Journalists must take account of this transformation, and remember that “what is making things different is human dominance as never before.”
At the investigative journalism website ProPublica, Abrahm Lustgarten and his colleagues enjoy the unusual luxury of creative, long-term reporting projects. Their freedom to spend literally years working a topic can lead to identifying a crisis before anyone else -- such as the dangers of drilling for natural gas -- and often involves looking behind the headlines of a major story to uncover all-important context.
Lustgarten describes ProPublica’s take on the Gulf oil spill, which “worked around the perimeter of what was happening,” focusing on BP’s drilling record, and inadequate government regulation. Since their story “was somewhat less sexy,” they offered “narrative focus and depth to engage readers.” ProPublica made its story urgent through a “drumbeat of communication…a steady stream of provocative and revealing stories,” and a longer-form investigative piece. Lustgarten sees the story now “probably at its most critical stage, months after the spill,” with mainstream “coverage at a virtual standstill.”
Andrea Pitzer believes in the power of narrative to help people understand public crises and public policy issues, but worries that “using storytelling in long-term crisis coverage” carries some risks. Journalists who target “established authorities” with stories may be viewed as “trying to sell something.” She advocates “tilting more heavily toward stories with teeth for an audience that already understands the basic problem.”
Pitzer embraces diverse media approaches to boost “game-changing narratives.” Visuals such as the photos from Abu Ghraib can have an instant impact on public opinion. She describes innovative websites such as TBD, which uses the Storify social media tool to aggregate perspectives on an event, “creating a moment by moment breakdown.” Statistics come alive and marry to stories with new forms of data visualization. Pitzer encourages reaching out to ordinary people and giving them a stake in their own narratives, demonstrating “where they fit into the larger arc.” Says Pitzer, “If we’re better at storytelling and giving them hooks … we’ll be presenting information so people really understand their choices.”
Categories: TemeTV
Relaunching Growth in Europe
José María Aznar finds it difficult to witness the calamitous decline of Spain, a nation he led to robust economic health as prime minister from 1996 to 2004. The gains during his administration have vanished following the international financial crisis. But the economic misfortunes of Spain and other European nations are actually long-standing, Aznar says, and represent a profound underlying “political, cultural and social crisis” suffered by the entire European continent.
Aznar recommends a “broad, historical perspective” to grasp this crisis. He begins after World War II, when European nations, pursuing a trio of goals -- “security, freedom and prosperity”-- joined the Atlantic alliance, committed to democratic forms of government, and established the welfare state. These countries pledged to support all three “pillars” simultaneously, because “the moment we sacrifice one, the other two are bound to be lost.” But over time, Aznar suggests, Europe’s will to sustain these fundamental principles flagged, and now many people have come to believe “that freedom, security and progress are something like national properties, perpetually guaranteed whatever you do.”
Europeans are divided between two starkly different world views, and in this division Aznar perceives the “true origin of our European crisis.” One ideology he describes as “utopian,” and involves a “cocktail of postmodern illusions” including the belief that societies will “just continue to improve,” that “social cohesion and well-being can be preserved without any effort whatsoever,” and that “one’s self is an endless source of economic rights (that) the government has an obligation to fulfill in exchange for nothing and for an indefinite period of time.” It is the world view of “progressive do-gooders and eternal teenagers.” Aznar sums up the alternative: a “realistic and responsible approach” to governing that encourages “civilization, freedom, science, culture and enterprise.”
The “European project” is also failing because member nations have not forcefully backed security and economic agreements that promote freedom and democracy as well as the competition, innovation and budget balancing that “would make welfare sustainable.” 300 million Europeans sharing a single currency cannot suffice to bring security, freedom and prosperity, all of which require “an intensity of political commitments,” says Aznar.
Europe can never return to its old ways of “irresponsible indebtedness,” says Aznar, nor can it indulge in “raising taxes indiscriminately” lest it lose out in global competition. He calls for “new, responsible leadership” to “undertake the task of explaining to citizens why it is essential to make structural reforms,” and help transform Europe into a “booming welfare society open to all, where individual responsibility, opportunity creation and social mobility” can come to the fore.
Aznar recommends a “broad, historical perspective” to grasp this crisis. He begins after World War II, when European nations, pursuing a trio of goals -- “security, freedom and prosperity”-- joined the Atlantic alliance, committed to democratic forms of government, and established the welfare state. These countries pledged to support all three “pillars” simultaneously, because “the moment we sacrifice one, the other two are bound to be lost.” But over time, Aznar suggests, Europe’s will to sustain these fundamental principles flagged, and now many people have come to believe “that freedom, security and progress are something like national properties, perpetually guaranteed whatever you do.”
Europeans are divided between two starkly different world views, and in this division Aznar perceives the “true origin of our European crisis.” One ideology he describes as “utopian,” and involves a “cocktail of postmodern illusions” including the belief that societies will “just continue to improve,” that “social cohesion and well-being can be preserved without any effort whatsoever,” and that “one’s self is an endless source of economic rights (that) the government has an obligation to fulfill in exchange for nothing and for an indefinite period of time.” It is the world view of “progressive do-gooders and eternal teenagers.” Aznar sums up the alternative: a “realistic and responsible approach” to governing that encourages “civilization, freedom, science, culture and enterprise.”
The “European project” is also failing because member nations have not forcefully backed security and economic agreements that promote freedom and democracy as well as the competition, innovation and budget balancing that “would make welfare sustainable.” 300 million Europeans sharing a single currency cannot suffice to bring security, freedom and prosperity, all of which require “an intensity of political commitments,” says Aznar.
Europe can never return to its old ways of “irresponsible indebtedness,” says Aznar, nor can it indulge in “raising taxes indiscriminately” lest it lose out in global competition. He calls for “new, responsible leadership” to “undertake the task of explaining to citizens why it is essential to make structural reforms,” and help transform Europe into a “booming welfare society open to all, where individual responsibility, opportunity creation and social mobility” can come to the fore.
Categories: TemeTV
Relaunching Growth in Europe
José María Aznar finds it difficult to witness the calamitous decline of Spain, a nation he led to robust economic health as prime minister from 1996 to 2004. The gains during his administration have vanished following the international financial crisis. But the economic misfortunes of Spain and other European nations are actually long-standing, Aznar says, and represent a profound underlying “political, cultural and social crisis” suffered by the entire European continent.
Aznar recommends a “broad, historical perspective” to grasp this crisis. He begins after World War II, when European nations, pursuing a trio of goals -- “security, freedom and prosperity”-- joined the Atlantic alliance, committed to democratic forms of government, and established the welfare state. These countries pledged to support all three “pillars” simultaneously, because “the moment we sacrifice one, the other two are bound to be lost.” But over time, Aznar suggests, Europe’s will to sustain these fundamental principles flagged, and now many people have come to believe “that freedom, security and progress are something like national properties, perpetually guaranteed whatever you do.”
Europeans are divided between two starkly different world views, and in this division Aznar perceives the “true origin of our European crisis.” One ideology he describes as “utopian,” and involves a “cocktail of postmodern illusions” including the belief that societies will “just continue to improve,” that “social cohesion and well-being can be preserved without any effort whatsoever,” and that “one’s self is an endless source of economic rights (that) the government has an obligation to fulfill in exchange for nothing and for an indefinite period of time.” It is the world view of “progressive do-gooders and eternal teenagers.” Aznar sums up the alternative: a “realistic and responsible approach” to governing that encourages “civilization, freedom, science, culture and enterprise.”
The “European project” is also failing because member nations have not forcefully backed security and economic agreements that promote freedom and democracy as well as the competition, innovation and budget balancing that “would make welfare sustainable.” 300 million Europeans sharing a single currency cannot suffice to bring security, freedom and prosperity, all of which require “an intensity of political commitments,” says Aznar.
Europe can never return to its old ways of “irresponsible indebtedness,” says Aznar, nor can it indulge in “raising taxes indiscriminately” lest it lose out in global competition. He calls for “new, responsible leadership” to “undertake the task of explaining to citizens why it is essential to make structural reforms,” and help transform Europe into a “booming welfare society open to all, where individual responsibility, opportunity creation and social mobility” can come to the fore.
Aznar recommends a “broad, historical perspective” to grasp this crisis. He begins after World War II, when European nations, pursuing a trio of goals -- “security, freedom and prosperity”-- joined the Atlantic alliance, committed to democratic forms of government, and established the welfare state. These countries pledged to support all three “pillars” simultaneously, because “the moment we sacrifice one, the other two are bound to be lost.” But over time, Aznar suggests, Europe’s will to sustain these fundamental principles flagged, and now many people have come to believe “that freedom, security and progress are something like national properties, perpetually guaranteed whatever you do.”
Europeans are divided between two starkly different world views, and in this division Aznar perceives the “true origin of our European crisis.” One ideology he describes as “utopian,” and involves a “cocktail of postmodern illusions” including the belief that societies will “just continue to improve,” that “social cohesion and well-being can be preserved without any effort whatsoever,” and that “one’s self is an endless source of economic rights (that) the government has an obligation to fulfill in exchange for nothing and for an indefinite period of time.” It is the world view of “progressive do-gooders and eternal teenagers.” Aznar sums up the alternative: a “realistic and responsible approach” to governing that encourages “civilization, freedom, science, culture and enterprise.”
The “European project” is also failing because member nations have not forcefully backed security and economic agreements that promote freedom and democracy as well as the competition, innovation and budget balancing that “would make welfare sustainable.” 300 million Europeans sharing a single currency cannot suffice to bring security, freedom and prosperity, all of which require “an intensity of political commitments,” says Aznar.
Europe can never return to its old ways of “irresponsible indebtedness,” says Aznar, nor can it indulge in “raising taxes indiscriminately” lest it lose out in global competition. He calls for “new, responsible leadership” to “undertake the task of explaining to citizens why it is essential to make structural reforms,” and help transform Europe into a “booming welfare society open to all, where individual responsibility, opportunity creation and social mobility” can come to the fore.
Categories: TemeTV